“If someone declares publicly that nuclear power would be needed in the baseload because of fluctuating energy from wind or sun in the grid, he has either not understood how an electricity grid or a nuclear power plant operates, or he consciously lies to the public. Nuclear energy and renewable energies cannot be combined.”—Siegmar Gabriel, then-Federal Environment Minister of Germany
This quote
was included in the anti-nuclear “World Nuclear Industry Status Report
2010-2011”, and it
introduced two points: the first being that “overcapacity kills efficiency
incentives,” and the second being that ‘renewables need flexible complementary
capacity.’ The implication here is that
because renewables need “flexible” capacity, and too much capacity isn’t
desirable, inflexible nuclear baseload is undesirable. If one buys into this premise, and if the
question arises, “which is better,” a nuclear supporter is born.
That
question doesn’t seem to come up very often.
Siegmar Gabriel, quoted above, is a German politician currently
chairing the Social Democratic Party of Germany (SPD). Hermann Scheer’s name was mentioned, in Ontario’s election
coverage, as being
brought, by David Suzuki, to meet Ontario’s Premier McGuinty; “The German parliamentarian (also
SPD), arrived in Mr. McGuinty’s office in the Ontario Legislature with a
blueprint for building a new economy from scratch." Scheer is noted as “one of the initiators of
the German Feed-in tariffs” in 1999.

The return
of 2 nuclear units at Pickering, and 2 at Bruce Power, between 2002 and 2005, boosted
Ontario nuclear production by almost exactly the reduced amount of fossil
fuel-fired generation.
There is no
rationally-based contest in terms of addressing climate change. Nuclear energy is vastly superior.
Ontario is
now experiencing the same events Germany experienced when adding wind
capacity. The previously noted World
Nuclear Report noted;
“...in October 2008, wind energy generation was so high that some non-renewable electricity had to be offered for “negative” prices on the power market because utilities could not reduce the output from nuclear and coal plants quickly enough—even though some 8 GW of nuclear capacity was off line for maintenance.Since then, negative electricity prices, legal in Germany since September 2008, have become a more frequent phenomenon: in the six months between September 2009 and February 2010, power prices in Germany dropped into the red on 29 days. Negative prices, a sort of financial penalty for inflexibility,reached stunning levels: on October 4, 2009, one power producer had to pay up to €1,500 per megawatt-hour (15 cents per kilowatt-hour) to get rid of its electricity.”Lunacy is required to twist that into an argument for wind turbines, but lunacy is worn like a favourite sweater by wind proponents. Returning again to the data available at entsoe, we also see the frequently noted pattern of wind-driven exports (in Ontario we sell exported power, on average, at less than half what the residents of Ontario pay):
![]() |
Solar Output Is far less likely to be exported |
We also see that growth in wind production, prior to the nuclear moratorium, had ceased to exist. With hindsight what surprises me about Ontario's unfolding, expensive, wind experience, is that the inability of wind output to produce reliable
supply, the impact of wind’s variability on pricing, and bloating supply (until
fossil plants age, or are retired for environmental reasons), was not only
known, and not contested, but it was wilfully turned into an argument to carry
on with the nuclear withdrawal experiment in Germany.
The German machine has become very good at twisting reality into an argument to will
an expansion of their desires – in this case ‘renewable’ energy. A
couple of years ago the press, perhaps at the urging of actual
environmentalists, caught onto the fact that carbon trading was actually
blocking possible gains in reduction GHG emissions. A Spiegal online article addressed the issue of the growth
in renewable driving down the cost of carbon credits in Europe:
“Germany was able to sell unused certificates across Europe -- to coal companies in countries like Poland or Slovakia, for example. Thanks to Germany's wind turbines, these companies were then able to emit more greenhouse gases than originally planned. Given the often lower efficiency of Eastern European power plants, this is anything but environmentally beneficial.”
Following the decision to spur on the renewable energy experiment
by discontinuing nuclear operations, the government has totally flipped this
argument. Tyler Hamilton reported on a
discussion he had with Dr. Harry Lehmann, executive director of Germany’ federal
environmental protection agency. Hamilton summed up the argument:
“Take nuclear out of the equation and the lower supply of emission-free energy will lead to an increase in the price of carbon. German utilities can choose to burn more coal, but it will cost them. For this reason, he says, the market will shift to less carbon-intensive energy sources, such as natural gas — and more renewables. The cap-and-trade system in Europe, in other words, will prevent the shutdown of nuclear plants in Germany from leading to increased reliance on coal.”The argument has been turned from increased wind only cheapens the carbon credits (preventing actual reductions in emissions), to reducing generation without emissions will drive up the price of carbon credits (preventing actual increases in emissions). That is the same reversal tactic we saw with windy periods driving down pricing and driving up exports somehow becoming an argument against nuclear.
The silliness of what is referred to, in my school of thought, as the 'you are rubber I am glue' argumentative technique emphasizes that the
will to increase renewables obviates, in the view of proponents, the arguments against doing so.